Judea
and Samaria is Israel
The Smoking Gun: Arab Immigration into Palestine , 1922-1931
In deep antiquity, particularly in Egypt , the early civilization where the arts were most strongly
developed, the visualization was aspective: that is the artist, working in
paint or low-relief sculpture, conveyed to his two-dimensional surface not so
much what he saw as what he knew was there.
Palestinian demography of the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries has never been just a matter of
numbers. It has always been—and consciously so—a front-line weapon used in a
life-and-death struggle for nationhood among two peoples living in what used to
be known as Palestine, each having competing ideologies and competing claims to
territorial inheritance and rights to national sovereignty.
The problem with staking so much on so
narrow a focus as past demography is that the data generated by demographers
and others since the early nineteenth century are so lacking in precision that,
in some matters of dispute concerning demography, "anyone's guess,"
as the saying goes, "is as good as any other." Or almost so. Of
course, people still engaged in this high-stakes game of Palestinian
demographic warfare will argue otherwise. With few exceptions, they insist that
their own sources are superior, their own estimates more scientific, and their
critics more ideological.
There are really two issues—or two
battlefronts—associated with estimating Palestinian demography. The first has
to do with sheer numbers, i.e., measuring over time the size of Palestine 's total and
subgroup populations. The second battlefront is considerably more contentious.
It is estimating the percentages of population growth among subgroups
attributed to natural increase and to immigration.
This immigration factor—or its
absence—is paramount. If a significant percent of a population is composed of
recent arrivals, then claims of historic tenancy are compromised. This explains
why Arab Palestinians and others use the term "intruder" to describe
the Jewish population of Palestine . The importance of Jewish immigration to the Jewish population of
Palestine in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century is undisputed.
But Jewish claims to territorial inheritance and to national sovereignty lay
elsewhere, in history rather than demography.
On the other hand, for Arab
Palestinians, the character of their demography is at the heart of their claim
to territorial inheritance and national sovereignty. Their contention, seen by
them as being beyond dispute, is that Arab Palestinians have deep and timeless
roots in that geography and that their own immigration into that geography has
at no time been consequential. To challenge that contention, then, is to
challenge their self-selected criterion for sovereignty.
That is to say, the character of Arab
Palestinian demography is the single most important piece of evidence
supporting the Arab Palestinian claim to territorial inheritance and national
sovereignty. The Arab Palestinian population—large or small, growing or not—is
determined, they insist, strictly by birth and death rates among Arab
Palestinians in Palestine, that is, by natural increase alone. This view of
their population origin is associated with their still more insular view of
"spatial stickiness," that is, their insistence as well that Arabs
have not only been disinclined to migrate out of or into Palestine but also
that Arab Palestinians have been disinclined to move from one region to another
within Palestine.
Before examining these contentions and
the competing Arab Palestinian population estimates offered by scholars in a
variety of disciplines, e.g., economics, sociology, demography, and history, it
may be useful to speculate on what anyone looking at late nineteenth- and early
twentieth-century Palestinian demography should expect to discover.
Disparities and Migration
If you were asked to guess which of two
corn farmers—a typical Iowa farm laborer or a typical Egyptian farm laborer—produced more
corn per acre, the probability is high that you would choose the Iowa farmer. And the
probability is just as high that you would be right—and for the right reasons.
Among the reasons you would offer to explain your choice are two: 1) the Iowa farmer has access
to more capital, and 2) the level of technology used on the Iowa farm is
considerably more advanced. This imposing combination of more capital and
higher levels of technology makes it no contest at all.
Your reasoning—the cause-effect
relationship between farm productivity, capital, and technology—is mapped in
Exhibit 1. The output curve Q measures the value of corn produced by a farm
laborer working with different quantities of capital. The more capital used by
the farm laborer, the higher is that laborer's productivity. For example,
working with $200 of farm machinery, the farm laborer produces $50 worth of
corn, point a. If the capital per laborer ratio increases from $200
to $250—economists call this increase "capital deepening"—the
laborer's productivity increases from $50 to $60, point b. The
curvature of Q—flattening with capital deepening—is explained by the law of
diminishing returns. Beyond some point, the productivity gains generated by
capital deepening rapidly approach zero.
But that is not the end of the story. More
advanced farm technology can shift the output curve upward from Q to Q'. That
is to say, still using $200 of capital but this time in a qualitatively
superior form of technology generates not $50 but $70 worth of corn,
point c. Some changes in technology can produce very dramatic
changes in productivity. Compare, for example, the productivity of a $1,000
computer printer to the productivity generated by $1,000 worth of pen and ink.
The moral is simple enough. The more
economies engage in capital deepening and technological change, the more they
will experience increasing labor productivity. Higher levels of labor
productivity make higher wage rates more affordable and also increase levels of
employment. Imagine, then, two adjacent economies, one heavily involved in
capital deepening and technological change, the other reluctant or unable to
change its technology or levels of capital deepening. The consequences are
inevitable. The productivity gap between the two economies widens, creating the
incentives for labor mobility.
Migratory Impulses
When dog bites man, it's not news. When
man bites dog, it's news. Similarly, when considerable regional disparities in
labor productivity, wage rates, and employment opportunities fail to generate
labor mobility—particularly among regions in close proximity—it is newsworthy.
That is to say, what really has to be explained is not why people move from
less attractive economies to more attractive economies, but why they don't.
Of course, not everybody moves. Lack of
information as well as physical, legal, political, religious, and social
barriers can work to impede movement. The elderly typically respond less to
economic incentives than the young, and peoples' levels of energy and personal
aspirations can differ markedly. These factors notwithstanding, it requires
hardly a stretch of the imagination to argue that the strength of the migratory
impulse among populations is highly correlated with differentials in labor
productivity and standards of living.
Historical and contemporary evidence
supporting migratory impulses, particularly among populations in the developing
economies of the world, is overwhelming.[1] While there is
every reason to suspect specific estimates—the methodology used in tracking
migrants is still fairly crude and in some cases politically motivated—the
picture is nonetheless clear. Some migratory routes have become virtual
highways. Since the mid-twentieth century, millions of North African and East
European migrants have left their native villages, towns, and cities for the
more productive and higher-paying jobs in western Europe. The European
Commission estimates that approximately one-half million migrants enter the
European Union (EU) illegally each year, almost as many as enter legally.[2] Such migration
flows are anything but unique. In Asia, the higher-paying employment
opportunities in the more industrially advanced economies of Japan, Hong Kong,
Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand, Taiwan, and South Korea have attracted an
estimated 6.5 million Asian migrants from the less technologically developed
economies.[3] Legal and
illegal migrant workers in 1998 in Japan alone numbered 1.35 million. The principal countries of origin
were China (234,000 legal and 38,000 illegal) and the Philippines (84,000 legal, 43,000 illegal).[4] Or consider
the Indonesia-Malaysia connection. In 2001, there were 850,000 Indonesians
working legally in Malaysia . An additional 350,000 to 400,000 were unauthorized.[5] That is no
surprise when you consider that Indonesian migrants earned $2 per day in Malaysia compared to the $0.28 per day they would have earned in Indonesia .[6]
The migratory impulse is alive and well
in the Americas for much the same reasons. The legal and illegal, daily and
nightly trek north across the Rio Grande by Mexicans
continues to be triggered by the glaring U.S.-Mexican wage disparities. A 1996
survey of 496 undocumented Mexican migrants to the United States showed that they averaged $278 per week compared to the $31 they
had earned at their last Mexican job.[7] While there
may be reason to question the specific numbers given for the Mexican migratory
flows, particularly the illegal estimates, there is little justification to
question the economic causes associated with the flow itself.
In 1970s Africa , oil-rich Nigeria absorbed millions of legal and illegal African migrants seeking
to escape the drought, famine, and poverty in their native Ghana , Niger , and Chad . The oil-price collapse in the 1980s forced Nigeria to reconsider its open-door immigration policy and by the
mid-1980s, approximately 2 million of these migrants—one million from Ghana alone—were obliged to leave.[8]
These references to contemporary
migrations are, of course, only the tip of the migratory iceberg. Adding up the
world's total migrations generates impressive but not surprising numbers. At
the beginning of the twenty-first century, the total number of persons living
outside of their countries of origin was estimated at over 150 million, of
which some 100 million—30 million undocumented—represent migrant workers and
their families.[9]
What seems to make sense in explaining
migratory flows for the rest of the world should make sense as well for the Middle East . And it does.
According to the International Labour Organization (ILO), Middle East migrant
workers—moving within and beyond the Middle East —make up approximately 9 percent of the world's 100-million total.[10] By 1987, as
many as 1.6 million Egyptians had emigrated to other Arab countries. Not
surprising, their principal destinations of choice were oil-rich economies. Iraq hosted 43 percent, Saudi Arabia and Kuwait , 39 percent.[11] The Kuwait war of 1990-91 brought about a dramatic shift in the hosting
economies of Egypt 's emigration. Iraq and Kuwait expelled most of their migrant populations during and following
that war and by 2000, Saudi Arabia had become the single most important host of Egypt 's now 2.7 million emigrants, absorbing as much as 34 percent of
the total. Libya rose to second place among Arab-hosting economies with 12 percent
and Jordan followed with 8 percent.[12]
Arab Palestinians, it appears, were no
less responsive than were Egyptians to the migratory impulse. According to 1998
United Nations Relief and Works Agency (UNRWA) estimates, there were 275,000
Arab Palestinians in Saudi Arabia, 38,000 in Kuwait (a dramatic drop from the
400,000 recorded before the Kuwait war), 74,000 in Libya, and over 100,000 in
other gulf countries.[13] Hundreds of
thousands left the Middle East entirely. Why should anyone suspect that Arab Palestinians would
behave any differently than Egyptians, or Mexicans, or Ghanaians, or Moroccans,
or Indonesians, or any other population facing regional inequalities in
technology, productivity, income, and employment? That the pull effect of wage
and employment disparities matters to Arab Palestinians is attested to not only
by the size of their migratory flows but also by the fact that very few Arab
Palestinians living in high-productivity Israel were part of that flow. In
fact, an estimated 40,000 Jordanians who entered Israel on tourist visas in 2000 have stayed on after their visas expired
to take advantage of the higher-paying employment opportunities afforded them
in Israel . [14]
Economic Growth, 1922-1931
It would seem reasonable to suppose
that for the same reasons Arab Palestinians and other Middle East populations
migrated from the less to the more attractive economies at the end of the
twentieth century, they would have done the same during the early decades of
the twentieth century. Two events distinguished the early years of
twentieth-century Palestine from its Middle Eastern neighbors: 1) the immigration into
Palestine of European Jews, accompanied by European capital and European
technology, and 2) the creation of the British Mandatory Government in Palestine whose
responsibilities included the economic development of Palestine . As a
result of the mandate conferred by the League of Nations , British capital
and British technology followed the British flag.
These two events generated a momentum
of economic activity that produced in Palestine a standard
of living previously unknown in the Middle East . Table 1 logs some of the critical factors contributing to the
economic dynamics in Palestine during the 1920s.
Table 1
Selected Indicators of Capital
Formation and Infrastructure Development: 1922-1931
Source: R. Szereszewski, Essays
on the Structure of the Jewish Economy in Palestine and Israel (Jerusalem: Maurice Falk Institute for Economic Research in
Israel, 1968), pp. 60, 82; and S. Himadeh, Economic Organization of Palestine (Beirut: American University at Beirut, 1938), pp. 282, 565.
(a) '000s of real LP measured at 1936 prices; (b) '000s LP, (c) real LP
measured at 1936 prices, (d) units of KWH sold, (e) kilometers of local
telegraph and telephone lines.
Capital stock grew at an annual rate of
14.1 percent, much of it a result of capital imports. The deepening of
capital—capital stock per laborer—accompanied the growth of capital stock. The
modernization process in the form of infrastructure development is illustrated
by the growth of road construction, electric power, and telephone
communications.[15] Table 1
represents the Palestinian version of both movements along the Qt curve
of Exhibit 1—capital deepening—and upward shifts in the curve which signal
technological change. The results were dramatic. Real net domestic product per
capita soared, doubling during 1922-31, from 19.4 LP (Palestine pounds) to
38.2 LP.
The success of these beginnings of
modernization could not have been lost on Arab Palestinians nor on Arabs living
in adjacent economies.[16] Table 2
contrasts the standards of living enjoyed by Arab Palestinians to the standards
in other Middle East economies.
Table 2
Economic Performance and
Standards of Living In Middle East Economies: 1932-1936
Source: F. Gottheil, "Arab
Immigration into Pre-State Israel : 1922-1931," Middle Eastern Studies, Oct. 1973,
p. 320. (a) British pound sterling, 1936; (b) in mils, 1933-5; (c)
International Units (IU), 1934-6; (d) IU, 1934-6.
Evidence for Arab Migration
There are several problems associated
with estimating Arab immigration into Palestine during the
1920s, the principal one being that Arab migration flows were, in the main,
illegal, and therefore unreported and unrecorded.[17] But they were
not entirely unnoticed.
Demographer U.O. Schmelz's analysis of
the Ottoman registration data for 1905 populations of Jerusalem and
Hebron kazas (Ottoman districts), by place of birth, showed that of
those Arab Palestinians born outside their localities of residence,
approximately half represented intra-Palestine movement—from areas of low-level
economic activity to areas of higher-level activity—while the other half
represented Arab immigration into Palestine itself, 43 percent originating in
Asia, 39 percent in Africa, and 20 percent in Turkey.[18] Schmelz
conjectured:
The above-average population growth of
the Arab villages around the city of Jerusalem , with its
Jewish majority, continued until the end of the mandatory period. This must
have been due—as elsewhere in Palestine under similar conditions—to in-migrants
attracted by economic opportunities, and to the beneficial effects of improved
health services in reducing mortality—just as happened in other parts of
Palestine around cities with a large Jewish population sector.[19]
While Schmelz restricted his research
of the 1905 Palestinian census to the official Ottoman registrations and used
these registrations with only minor critical comment, he did acknowledge that
"stable population models assume the absence of external migrations, a
condition which was obviously not met by all the subpopulations" that
Schmelz enumerated.[20]
Like U.O. Schmelz, Roberto Bachi
expressed some reservation about the virtual non-existence of data and
discussion concerning migration into and within Palestine . He writes:
Between 1800 and 1914, the Muslim
population had a yearly average increase in the order of magnitude of roughly
6-7 per thousand. This can be compared to the very crude estimate of about 4
per thousand for the "less developed countries" of the world (in Asia , Africa , and Latin America ) between 1800 and
1910. It is possible that part of the growth of the Muslim population
was due to immigration.[21]
Although Bachi did not pursue the
linkage between undocumented immigration into Palestine and the 6 (or 7) to 4
per thousand differential in growth rates between Palestine and the other less
developed countries (LDCs), the idea that at least one-third of Palestine's
population growth may be attributed to immigration is—using Bachi's own growth
rate differentials—not an entirely unreasonable one.
Lacking verifiable evidence did not
prevent Bachi from stating the obvious concerning internal migration within Palestine :
The great economic development of the
coastal plains—largely due to Jewish immigration—was accompanied both in
1922-1931 and in 1931-1944 by a much stronger increase of the Muslim and
Christian populations in this region than that registered in other regions.
This was probably due to two reasons: stronger decrease in mortality of the
non-Jewish population in the neighborhood of Jewish areas and internal
migration toward the more developed zones.[22]
In the footnote accompanying this
quote, Bachi writes: "As no statistics are available for internal
migration, this conclusion has been obtained from indirect evidence."[23] Bachi's
footnote is instructive. The "indirect evidence" he referred to no
doubt included his understanding of the important role economics plays in
explaining demographic movements. While appreciating the value of Ottoman
registrations and British mandatory government censuses in providing estimates
of Palestinian demography, they were, in his judgment, still crude and incomplete.
Reference to Arab immigration into Palestine during the
1920s is made as well in the British mandatory government's annual compilation
of statistical data on population. The Palestine Blue Book, 1937, for example,
provides time series demographic statistics whose annual estimates are based on
extrapolations from its 1922 census.[24] The footnote
accompanying the table on population of Palestine reads:
There has been unrecorded illegal
immigration of both Jews and Arabs in the period since the census of 1931, but
it is clear that, since it cannot be recorded, no estimate of its volume is
possible.[25]
The 1935 British report to the League of Nations noted that:
One thousand five hundred and
fifty-seven persons (including 565 Jews) who, having made their way into the
country surreptitiously, were later detected, were sentenced to imprisonment
for their offence and recommended for deportation.[26]
The number who "made their way
into the country surreptitiously" and undetected was neither estimated nor
mentioned.
Historian Gad Gilbar's observation on
Ruth Kark's contribution to his edited volume Ottoman Palestine , 1800-1914, touches on the issue of Arab
immigration into and within Palestine . He relates her ideas in "The Rise and Decline of Coastal
Towns in Palestine " to Charles Issawi's thesis concerning the role of minority
groups and foreigners in the development of Middle Eastern towns. Explaining
why no other Palestinian cities grew as rapidly as Jaffa and Haifa did during the
final three decades of the Ottoman rule, Gilbar writes: "Both attracted
population from the rural and urban surroundings and immigrants from outside Palestine ."[27]
Each piece of the demographic puzzle by
itself may reveal no identifiable picture. But given a multiplicity of such
pieces, an image does begin to appear. The Royal Institute for International
Affairs adds another piece. Commenting on the growth of the Palestinian
population during the decades of the 1920s and 1930s it reports: "The
number of Arabs who have entered Palestine illegally
from Syria and Transjordan is unknown. But probably considerable."[28] And C.S.
Jarvis, governor of the Sinai from 1923-36, adds yet another:
This illegal immigration was not only
going on from the Sinai, but also from Trans-Jordan and Syria, and it is very
difficult to make a case out for the misery of the Arabs if at the same time
their compatriots from adjoining states could not be kept from going in to
share that misery.[29]
Estimating Real Numbers
The derivation of Palestine migration
estimates in this section is based on an uncomplicated imputation theory.
Migration becomes a residual claimant for numbers not explained by a
population-estimating model based on known initial population stocks and known
sets of birth and death rates for that population. In this way, expected
population stocks can be derived for any set of subsequent years.
The value of the model depends, of
course, on the reliability of the estimates given for initial population stocks
and for the rates associated with natural increase. Therein lies the problem
with estimating Arab immigration into Palestine . The model
itself may be simple and applicable, but its usefulness—as with all estimating
models—is contingent upon the quality of the data inputs. That quality in the
case of Palestinian migration is compromised by the explicit neglect of illegal
entrants. If illegal migrants and subsequently illegal residents escaped the
census taker, how could the census account for them? It couldn't and didn't.
It is not surprising then that the
British census data produce an Arab Palestinian population growth for 1922-31
that turns out to be generated by natural increase and legal migrations alone.
Applying a 2.5 per annum growth rate[30] to a
population stock of 589,177 for 1922 generates a 1931 population estimate of
735,799 or 97.6 percent of the 753,822 recorded in the 1931 census. Does the
imputation model then "prove" that illegal immigration into Palestine was
inconsequential during 1922-31? Not at all. A footnote accompanying the
census's population time series acknowledges the presence in Palestine of illegal
Arab immigration. But because it could not be recorded, no estimate of its
numbers was included in the census count.[31] Ignoring
illegal migrants does not mean they don't exist.
Setting illegal immigration into Palestine aside, the
imputation model does generate substantial migrations of Arab
Palestinians within Palestine itself and
confirms what many demographers, historians, government administrators, and
economists have alluded to: the migration of Arab Palestinians from villages,
towns, and cities of low economic opportunity to villages, towns, and cities of
higher economic opportunity.
Which towns, villages, and cities
offered the higher economic opportunity? Analyzing the 1922 and 1931
demographic data by sub-district and separating those sub-districts of
Palestine that eventually became 1948 Israel—that is, sub-districts that had
relatively large Jewish populations (with accompanying Jewish capital and
modern technology)—from those that were not designated as part of 1948 Israel,
identified not only the direction of Arab Palestinian migration within
Palestine but its magnitude as well.[32]
The Arab Palestinian populations within
those sub-districts that eventually became Israel increased from 321,866 in 1922 to 463,288 in 1931 or by 141,422.
Applying the 2.5 per annum natural rate of population growth to the 1922 Arab
Palestinian population generates an expected population size
for 1931 of 398,498 or 64,790 less than the actual population recorded in the
British census. By imputation, this unaccounted population increase must have
been either illegal immigration not accounted for in the British census and/or
registered Arab Palestinians moving from outside the Jewish-identified
sub-districts to those sub-districts so identified. This 1922-31 Arab migration
into the Jewish sub-districts represented 11.8 percent of the total 1931 Arab
population residing in those sub-districts and as much as 36.8 percent of its
1922-31 growth.
That over 10 percent of the 1931 Arab
Palestinian population in those sub-districts that eventually became Israel had immigrated to those sub-districts within the 1922-31 years is
a datum of considerable significance. It is consistent with the fragmentary
evidence of illegal migration to and within Palestine; it supports the idea of
linkage between economic disparities and migratory impulses—a linkage
universally accepted; it undercuts the thesis of "spatial stickiness"
attributed by some scholars to the Arab Palestinian population of the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries; and it provides strong circumstantial
evidence that the illegal Arab immigration into Palestine, like that within
Palestine, was of consequence as well.
Denying the Evidence
As compelling as the arguments and
evidence supporting consequential illegal immigration may be to some scholars,
they are clearly unconvincing to others. The single most cited contemporary
publication on Palestinian demography is Justin McCarthy's 1990 The
Population of Palestine. Of McCarthy's 43 pages of descriptive
analysis—supplemented by 188 pages of demographic tables copied directly from
Ottoman, European, and Jewish source materials—slightly more than one and a
half pages are devoted to Arab immigration into and within Palestine during the
Ottoman period, and a similar one and a half pages are devoted to Arab
immigration during the succeeding mandate period.[33] According to
McCarthy, these few pages offer enough critical analysis to close the lid on
the "infamous" immigration thesis.
Consider first McCarthy's analysis of
Arab immigration during the Ottoman period. That he finds no illegal
immigration of consequence is not surprising because McCarthy uses official
Ottoman registration lists that, by the nature of its classifications, take no
account of the unreported, illegal immigration. That is to say, if you look in
a haystack for a needle that wasn't put there, the probability is high you
won't find it. It is strange that that idea had not occurred to McCarthy.
Choosing to focus on the official registration lists allows him to write:
From the analysis of rates of increase
of the Muslim population of the three Palestiniansanjaks [Ottoman
sub-provinces], one can say with certainty that Muslim
immigration after 1870 was small.[34]
Reflecting elsewhere on the possibility
that the immigration may have occurred over an extended period of time,
McCarthy writes: "To postulate such an immigration … stretches the limits
of credulity."[35]
McCarthy's treatment of the linkage
between economic disparities and migration impulses appears to be even more
disingenuous. He writes: "The question of the relative economic development
of Palestine in Ottoman times is not a matter to be discussed here."[36] Nor is it
considered anywhere else in his book. That is to say, McCarthy does not contest
the linkage so much as ignore its relevance to the Palestinian situation.[37]
His dismissal of Arab immigration into Palestine during the
mandate period is based on a set of assumptions concerning illegal immigration
that is both restrictive and unsubstantiated. He contends that even if the
illegal immigrants were unreported on entry, their deaths in Palestine would have
been registered. So too, he argues, would their children born in Palestine . Deriving
estimates based on such registrations, he arrives at this conclusion:
immigration was minimal.[38] But he
provides no evidence to show that these supposed registrations
of births and deaths were actually made. Had McCarthy considered the fact that
detection of illegal immigration during the mandate period resulted in
imprisonment and deportation and that immigrants, aware of this, may have
avoided any formal registration of deaths and births, he would have had to
revise his assessment of illegal immigration.
Perhaps the more serious charge against
McCarthy's analysis of Arab immigration is his use of Roberto Bachi's
estimates. McCarthy's numbers are based, in part, on Bachi's reporting of 900
illegal Arab immigrants per year over the period 1931-45.[39] But McCarthy
misrepresents what Bachi's estimate is meant to show. Bachi is careful to
identify his 900-per-year illegal Arab immigration estimate as only those
discovered by the mandatory authorities. Illegal Arab immigration that went
undetected and unreported is not included. He writes:
A detailed analysis presented in
Appendix 6.5B on the basis of the registration of part of the illegal
migratory traffic, discovered by the Palestine police, shows that legal
movements (as reflected in Tables 9.4-9.7) constituted only a small fraction of
total Muslim immigration.[40]
To emphasize this point, Bachi writes:
"It is hardly credible that illegal movements which were actually
discovered included all the illegal entrances which actually occurred, or even
the majority of them."[41] As a result,
Bachi can only conclude that "in the present state of knowledge, we have
beenunable to even guess the size of total immigration."[42]
Such a cautionary comment finds no
place in McCarthy's analysis or conclusions. Using Bachi's estimates
inappropriately, deriving estimates based solely on registration lists, and
ignoring completely the linkages between regional economic disparities and
migratory impulses, McCarthy confidently concludes,
the vast majority of the Palestinians
resident in 1947 were the sons and daughters who were living in Palestine before
modern Jewish immigration began. There is no reason to believe that they
were not the sons and daughters of Arabs who had been in Palestine for many centuries.[43]
Every Reason to Believe
Therein lies the ideological warfare
concerning claims to territorial inheritance and national sovereignty. Contrary
to McCarthy's findings or wishes, there is every reason to believe that
consequential immigration of Arabs into and within Palestine occurred
during the Ottoman and British mandatory periods. Among the most compelling
arguments in support of such immigration is the universally acknowledged and
practiced linkage between regional economic disparities and migratory impulses.
The precise magnitude of Arab
immigration into and within Palestine is, as Bachi noted, unknown. Lack of completeness in Ottoman
registration lists and British Mandatory censuses, and the immeasurable
illegal, unreported, and undetected immigration during both periods make any
estimate a bold venture into creative analysis. In most cases, those venturing
into the realm of Palestinian demography—or other demographic analyses based on
very crude data—acknowledge its limitations and the tentativeness of the conclusions
that may be drawn.
Fred M. Gottheil is a professor in the department of economics, University of Illinois .
[1] On
June 20, 2002, there were 2,840,000 "migration" entries on the
Internet (Google); 319,000 for Asian migration alone, 282,000 for African
migration, 291,000 for Middle Eastern migration, 78,000 for Arab migration, and
69,000 for Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development migration. The
International Labor Organization (ILO) and the United Nations have published
extensively on the subject.
[2] Reuters,June 18, 2002 .
[3] TheJakarta Post, Mar. 3, 2000 .
[4] Peter Stalker, Growing Global Migration and Its Implications for the United States(Washington : National Intelligence Council, Mar. 2001), p. 38, table 3, athttp://www.cia.gov/nic/graphics/migration.pdf.
[5] Migration News, Oct. 2001, p. 2., at http://migration.ucdavis.edu/mn/archive_mn/oct_2001-16mn.html.
[6] TheJakarta Post, Mar. 3, 2000 .
[7] Ibid.
[8] Nicholas Van Hear, Consequences of the Forced Mass Repatriation of Migrant Communities: Recent Cases fromWest Africa and the Middle East (Geneva: U.N. Research Institute for Social Development,
1992), p. 1.
[9] Patrick Taran and David Nii Addy, "Global Overview Trends in Labour Migration, Standards and Policies with Reference to West Africa," ILO International Migration Policy Seminar for West Africa, Dakar, Senegal, Dec. 18-21, 2001, at http://www.december18.net/paper35Dakar.htm.
[10] Ibid.
[11] The Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics,Cairo , provides these
statistics athttp://www.frcu.eun.eg/www/homepage/popin/eeea.htm.
[12] ILO Migration DataBase , Egypt : Table 11, "Nationals Abroad by Sex and by Host Country,
Absolute Numbers, 1986-2001." See also "Egyptian Guest Workers in the
Gulf," Migration News, July 1995, at http://migration.ucdavis.edu/mn/archive_mn/jul_1995-22mn.html.
[13] Ahmad Sidqi al Dajani, The Future of the Exiled Palestinians in the Settlements Agreement(London : Palestinian Return Center , Oct. 2000), at http://www.prc.org.uk/english/ext-pals-eng.htm.
[14] TheJerusalem Post, July 4, 2001 .
[15] Roberto Bachi, The Population ofIsrael (Jerusalem: Institute of Contemporary Jewry, Hebrew
University, 1974), p. 45.
[16] Ibid., p. 46
[17] A second issue contributing to the dearth of Arab migration data and analysis was that scholarly research and interest in the region focused on the more legal and documented, more prevalent, and more politically significant Jewish immigration. While Arab immigration may have been obvious and even predictable, it would have been less noteworthy at the time.
[18] U.O. Schmelz, "Population Characteristics ofJerusalem and Hebron Regions According
to Ottoman Census of 1905," in Gar G. Gilbar, ed., Ottoman Palestine : 1800-1914 (Leiden: Brill, 1990), p.
42.
[19] Ibid., pp. 32-3. Emphasis added.
[20] Ibid., p. 61. Emphasis added. Elsewhere, he grants that "the censuses were taken by teams of local mukhtars and other functionaries" and "that may have created conflicts of motive when the authorities, by threat of penalty, exacted reports from local dignitaries (the mukhtars) which the population may have had an interest in evading." (pp. 18-9).
[21] Bachi, Population ofIsrael , pp. 34-5. Emphasis added.
[22] Ibid., p. 51. Emphasis added.
[23] Ibid.
[24]Palestine Blue Book, 1937 (Jerusalem:
British Mandatory Government Printer, 1938), p. 140.
[25] Ibid. Emphasis added. ThePalestine Blue Book, 1928 actually
offers an estimate. It says: "The total population 816,064 is probably
understated by 20,000-25,000 due to unrecorded immigration." (p. 143.)
Three years later, the Palestine Blue Book, 1931 uses
the same estimate and the same wording but for a different size population:
"The total population 946,463 is probably understated by 20,000-25,000 due
to unrecorded immigration." (p. 146.) By 1937, the estimate was dropped in
favor of "no estimate of its volume is possible."
[26] Report by His Majesty's Government in the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland to the Council of the League of Nations on the Administration of Palestine and Trans-Jordan for the Year 1935 (London: His Majesty's Stationary Office, n.d.), p. 14.
[27] Gar G. Gilbar, "Economy and Society inPalestine at the
Close of the Ottoman Period: A Diversity of Change," in Ottoman Palestine , 1800-1914, p. 3.
[28]Great Britain and Palestine , 1915-1945, Information Paper
no. 20, 3d ed. (London: Royal Institute for International Affairs, 1946), p.
64.
[29] C.S. Jarvis, "Palestine ," United Empire (London ), 28 (1937): 633.
[30] The 2.5 growth rate is derived from the following table for annual rates of natural increase of Muslim population.
[2] Reuters,
[3] The
[4] Peter Stalker, Growing Global Migration and Its Implications for the United States(
[5] Migration News, Oct. 2001, p. 2., at http://migration.ucdavis.edu/mn/archive_mn/oct_2001-16mn.html.
[6] The
[7] Ibid.
[8] Nicholas Van Hear, Consequences of the Forced Mass Repatriation of Migrant Communities: Recent Cases from
[9] Patrick Taran and David Nii Addy, "Global Overview Trends in Labour Migration, Standards and Policies with Reference to West Africa," ILO International Migration Policy Seminar for West Africa, Dakar, Senegal, Dec. 18-21, 2001, at http://www.december18.net/paper35Dakar.htm.
[10] Ibid.
[11] The Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics,
[12] ILO Migration Data
[13] Ahmad Sidqi al Dajani, The Future of the Exiled Palestinians in the Settlements Agreement(
[14] The
[15] Roberto Bachi, The Population of
[16] Ibid., p. 46
[17] A second issue contributing to the dearth of Arab migration data and analysis was that scholarly research and interest in the region focused on the more legal and documented, more prevalent, and more politically significant Jewish immigration. While Arab immigration may have been obvious and even predictable, it would have been less noteworthy at the time.
[18] U.O. Schmelz, "Population Characteristics of
[19] Ibid., pp. 32-3. Emphasis added.
[20] Ibid., p. 61. Emphasis added. Elsewhere, he grants that "the censuses were taken by teams of local mukhtars and other functionaries" and "that may have created conflicts of motive when the authorities, by threat of penalty, exacted reports from local dignitaries (the mukhtars) which the population may have had an interest in evading." (pp. 18-9).
[21] Bachi, Population of
[22] Ibid., p. 51. Emphasis added.
[23] Ibid.
[24]
[25] Ibid. Emphasis added. The
[26] Report by His Majesty's Government in the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland to the Council of the League of Nations on the Administration of Palestine and Trans-Jordan for the Year 1935 (London: His Majesty's Stationary Office, n.d.), p. 14.
[27] Gar G. Gilbar, "Economy and Society in
[28]
[29] C.S. Jarvis, "
[30] The 2.5 growth rate is derived from the following table for annual rates of natural increase of Muslim population.
"As I lived
in Judea aka part of Palestine , everyone I knew
could trace their heritage back to the original country their great
grandparents came from. Everyone knew their origin was not from the Canaanites,
but ironically, this is the kind of stuff our education in the Middle East included. The
fact is that today's Arab-Palestinians are immigrants from the surrounding
nations! I grew up well knowing the history and origins of today's Arab-Palestinians
as being from Yemen , Saudi Arabia , Morocco , Christians from Greece , Muslim Sherkas
from Russia , Muslims from Bosnia , and the
Jordanians next door. My grandfather, who was a dignitary in Bethlehem , almost lost his
life by Abdul Qader Al-Husseni (the leader of the Arab-Palestinian revolution)
after being accused of selling land to Jews. He used to tell us that his
village Beit Sahur (The Shepherds Fields) in Bethlehem County was empty before
his father settled in the area with six other families. The town has now grown
to 30,000 inhabitants".
- Walid Shoebat, an "ex-Palestinian" Arab -
- Walid Shoebat, an "ex-Palestinian" Arab -
No comments:
Post a Comment